Rethinking Majority Rule: The Urgent Need to Revise Sri Lanka's Presidential Elections Act
The flaw in Preference voting electing an Executive President
Laws must be clear and free from ambiguities, yet the Presidential Elections Act (No. 15 of 1981) of Sri Lanka falls short of this standard. This article highlights a significant flaw in the Act concerning the preference voting system used in presidential elections. Under the current law, preferences are disregarded if a candidate secures over 50% of valid votes, a situation that has been common since the Act's implementation. However, the political landscape in Sri Lanka has shifted dramatically in the past three years, exacerbated by the COVID-19 pandemic and the country's economic downturn. It is now increasingly unlikely for any candidate to achieve such a majority. This brings to light a critical issue: when preferences are counted due to no candidate reaching the 50% threshold, the eventual winner may not represent the majority's mandate. This flaw underscores the need for a thorough review and potential revision of the Act to ensure it aligns with the democratic principle of majority rule.
Election Results: Past and 2024 opinion polls
These give percentages of votes in actual presidential elections.
year | UNP/NDF | SLFP/SLPP/PA | JVP/NPP | SLTC | SLMP | first two | bal |
1982 | 52.9% | 39.1% | 4.2% | 2.7% | 0.0% | 92.0% | 8.0% |
1988 | 50.4% | 45.0% | 0.0% | 0.0% | 4.6% | 95.4% | 4.6% |
1994 | 35.9% | 62.3% | 0.0% | 0.0% | 0.0% | 98.2% | 1.8% |
1999 | 42.7% | 51.1% | 4.1% | 0.0% | 0.0% | 93.8% | 6.2% |
2005 | 48.4% | 50.3% | 0.0% | 0.0% | 0.0% | 98.7% | 1.3% |
2010 | 40.2% | 57.9% | 0.0% | 0.0% | 0.0% | 98.0% | 2.0% |
2015 | 51.3% | 47.6% | 0.0% | 0.0% | 0.0% | 98.9% | 1.1% |
2019 | 42.0% | 52.3% | 3.2% | 0.0% | 0.0% | 94.2% | 5.8% |
This gives a set of opinion polls for the 2024 presidential election.
(Polling firm - Institute for Health Policy)
Date | DissanayakeNPP | PremadasaSJB | Wickremesinghe UNP | SLPP | Lead | Margin of error | Sample size | first 2 total | others |
Dec-23 | 50.0% | 33.0% | 9.0% | 8.0% | 17.0% | ±1–4% | 14941 | 83.0% | 17.0% |
Oct-23 | 51.0% | 30.0% | 13.0% | 6.0% | 21.0% | ±1–4% | 567 | 81.0% | 19.0% |
Sep-23 | 46.0% | 29.0% | 17.0% | 8.0% | 17.0% | ±1–3% | 599 | 75.0% | 25.0% |
Aug-23 | 38.0% | 35.0% | 18.0% | 9.0% | 3.0% | ±1–3% | 556 | 73.0% | 27.0% |
Jul-23 | 39.0% | 33.0% | 19.0% | 9.0% | 6.0% | ±1–3% | 466 | 72.0% | 28.0% |
Jun-23 | 40.0% | 35.0% | 15.0% | 9.0% | 5.0% | ±1–3% | 506 | 75.0% | 25.0% |
May-23 | 38.0% | 34.0% | 18.0% | 10.0% | 4.0% | ±1–4% | 630 | 72.0% | 28.0% |
Apr-23 | 45.0% | 37.0% | 13.0% | 6.0% | 8.0% | ±1–4% | 580 | 82.0% | 18.0% |
Mar-23 | 48.0% | 37.0% | 11.0% | 4.0% | 11.0% | ±1–5% | 521 | 85.0% | 15.0% |
This clearly shows the following points:
1. So far it was not necessary to count the preferences since over 50% majority was obtained.
2. In 2024 most probably a preference count will be necessary.
3. In Previous elections the first two candidates got more than 90% of the votes, 2024 it may come down to 70%
4. 2024 parties other than the first two might get about 30% of the votes.
5. Practical first-hand experience as an election official officiated many elections, there exists confusion among voters marking preferences, and nonuniformity by the election officials in the manual preference counting, though it was not ultimately necessary some preemptive procedures were adopted. With a tight election, there will be a nightmare in counting preferences.
The presidential voting system combines first-past-the-post with a modified form of instant-runoff voting (IRV) for instances where no candidate secures a majority of over 50%. In this system, voters' second preferences are considered for the least successful candidate during the initial count. This innovative method aims to ensure the elected leader receives wider support, potentially minimizing the election of a divisive figure with a narrow support base. Nevertheless, there are complexities to be navigated, particularly when selecting a leader with substantial authority. The system's efficacy is questioned when a country with a strong democratic foundation elects an executive president who wields considerable power. This predicament was evident in Sri Lanka's introduction of the executive presidency, where historically, a split vote led to concerns over the legitimacy of a leader's mandate. Presently, with major parties losing popularity, there looms the risk of electing a president without a clear mandate, highlighting a potential flaw in the system.
Example 1 - Where all 3 candidates take the near the same number of votes
votes for A -34, this 34 divided between preferences B 14 & C 20 |
votes for B -33, this 33 divided between preferences A 17 & C 16 |
votes for C -33, this 33 divided between preferences A 15& B 18 |
Candidate / Votes & Preferences | for A | for B | for C |
Voter's First Choice: A | 34 | 14 | 20 |
Voter's First Choice: B | 17 | 33 | 16 |
Voter's First Choice: C | 15 | 18 | 33 |
Eliminated Candidate | Remaining Candidate | Remaining Candidate votes | Eliminated Candidate Preferences | Total Votes & Preferences | highest | Winner |
A | B | 33 | 14 | 47 | 53 | |
A | C | 33 | 20 | 53 | 53 | C |
B | A | 34 | 17 | 51 | 51 | A |
B | C | 33 | 16 | 49 | 51 | |
C | A | 34 | 15 | 49 | 51 | |
C | B | 33 | 18 | 51 | 51 | B |
Example 2 - where 2 candidates take nearly 50% and other low
votes for A -49 this 49 divided between preferences B 14 & C 35 |
votes for B -48, this 48 divided between preferences A 2 & C 46 |
votes for C -3, this 3 divided between preferences A 1 & C 2 |
Candidate / Votes & Preferenc33 | for A | for B | for C |
Voter's First Choice: A | 49 | 14 | 35 |
Voter's First Choice: B | 2 | 48 | 46 |
Voter's First Choice: C | 1 | 2 | 3 |
Eliminated Candidate | Remaining Candidate | Remaining Candidate votes | Eliminated Candidate Preferences | Total Votes & Preferences | higest | Winner |
A | B | 48 | 14 | 62 | 62 | B |
A | C | 3 | 35 | 38 | 62 | |
B | A | 49 | 2 | 51 | 51 | A |
B | C | 3 | 46 | 49 | 51 | |
C | A | 49 | 1 | 50 | 50 | A |
C | B | 48 | 2 | 50 | 50 | B |
Example 3 - one candidate takes a very high number while the other 2 very low
votes for A -90 this 90 divided between preferences B 14 & C 76 |
votes for B -8 this 8 divided between preferences A 2 & C 6 |
votes for C -2, this 2 divided between preferences A 1 & B 1 |
Candidate / Votes & Preferences | for | for B | for C |
Voter's First Choice: A | 90 | 14 | 76 |
Voter's First Choice: B | 2 | 8 | 6 |
Voter's First Choice: C | 1 | 1 | 2 |
Eliminated Candidate | Remaining Candidate | Remaining Candidate votes | Eliminated Candidate Preferences | Total Votes & Preferences | highest | Winner |
A | B | 8 | 14 | 22 | 78 | |
A | C | 2 | 76 | 78 | 78 | C |
B | A | 90 | 2 | 92 | 92 | A |
B | C | 2 | 6 | 8 | 92 | |
C | A | 90 | 1 | 91 | 91 | A |
C | B | 8 | 1 | 9 | 91 |
To amend the presidential election system in Sri Lanka, such as abandoning the preference method for a simpler model that doesn't mandate an absolute majority, would require a constitutional amendment. This process involves not only a two-thirds parliamentary approval but also possibly a public referendum since such a change would affect the fundamental democratic rights enshrined in the constitution. The constitution needs a change to reflect the correct mandate of the people
DIRECTIONS FOR THE GUIDANCE OF VOTERS
When there are two candidates: mark the figure “1” in the space provided for the purpose on the right-hand side of the ballot paper opposite the symbol and the name of the candidate for whom he votes.
When there are three candidates: specify his second preference by making the figure “2” opposite the symbol and the name of the candidate.
When there are more than three candidates: specify his second and third preferences, by marking figure “2” to indicate his second preference and figure ‘3” to indicate his third preference opposite the symbol and the name of the candidate
Section 57. Procedure where no candidate receives an absolute majority
(1) Where no candidate has received more than one-half of the valid votes cast at the election, the Commissioner shall
(a) where there are three candidates at the election—
(i) eliminate from the contest the candidate who has received the lowest number of votes,
and
(ii) direct each returning officer to take such steps as may be necessary to count the second preference of each voter whose vote has been for the candidate eliminated under subparagraph (i) of this paragraph, as a vote in favor of one or the other of the remaining two candidates;
or
(b) where there are more than three candidates at the election—
(i) eliminate from the contest the candidates other than the candidates who received the highest and second highest number of votes,
and
(ii) direct each returning officer to take such steps as may be necessary—
(aa) to count the second preference of each voter whose vote had been for a candidate eliminated under subparagraph (1) of this paragraph, if it is for one or the other of the remaining two candidates, as a vote in favor of such remaining candidate;
and
(bb) where the second preference of a voter is not counted under this sub-paragraph, to count the third preference of such voter if it is for one or the other of the remaining two candidates, as a vote in favor of such remaining candidate.
2.
Septation of ballot
papers in 50 ballot bundles with a vote single candidate. This is done for each
of the candidates. And bundles are piled up near to the chief counting officer.
3.
The count for each
candidate is recorded and sent to the Retaining Officer.
4.
The Retaining officer
will transmit it to the Election Commissioner.
5. The Election Commissioner
will tally all results and see whether a candidate has obtained more than 50%
of valid votes.
6.
If a candidate
obtains over 50% he is declared as the winner, which was the case in all 10
presidential elections conducted in the country after 1978.(1982, 1988, 1994, 1995, 1999, 2000, 2005, 2010, 2015,
2019)
7.
However, if none of
the counts did not need the preference count.
8.
In a meeting
explanation of conducting the count with the Election Commissioner, I as a
Chief Counting Officer pose a question to him “When counting
preference if the counting officer detected that the main vote was for another
candidate, though it is in the bundle of some other candidate?”. He without
explaining the procedure to correct the anomaly, just sidestepped by stating “Then
what is the quality of your count?”. Practically what the election officials do
is treat it as a spoiled vote. Though this is illegal, so far it not not affected
the final outcome of the poll.
1.
Thou this is a
hypothetical mistake, when you take into account that 1550 centers and over
20,000 officials doing the count, waken till deep into the night, doing a
manual counting, mistakes can happen, and there should be a method of
rectifying these mistakes.
2.
However, rectifying a
single mistake is a huge task, it has to be reported to the Election
Commissioner, he needs to reevaluate the second place, and report to all
counting stations to change the second place.
3.
If mistakes are
detected there will be a never-ending count.
4.
This will be the case
when the leading candidates are 3 or more with near number of votes.
In the quest for democratic ideals, electoral systems serve as the backbone of representation and governance. A fascinating proposition emerges from a unique voting mechanism, blending the straightforwardness of first-past-the-post with the nuanced consideration of instant-runoff voting. This hybrid model, particularly in the context of electing an executive president with significant authority, merits a deep dive into its mechanics, potential anomalies, and broader implications for a democratic franchise.
The Mechanics of the Proposed Voting System
At the heart of this system lies a dual-layer approach to capturing voter preferences. Initially, it operates on a simple majority basis, where the candidate securing more than 50% of the votes is declared the winner. However, in the absence of such a majority, the system pivots to consider voters' second preferences. Specifically, the votes for the least popular candidate are redistributed based on these preferences, potentially altering the outcome in favor of a candidate with broader, albeit secondary, support.
Anomalies and Unintended Consequences
One of the most intriguing aspects of this system is its capacity to produce outcomes that challenge conventional wisdom. For instance, it's conceivable that a candidate, initially in third place, could emerge victorious after the redistribution of second preferences. This scenario underscores the system's aim to ensure a leader with wide appeal, albeit it also highlights potential anomalies:
- Non-majority President: The possibility of electing a president who didn't secure an initial majority raises questions about the mandate's strength. In systems granting substantial power to the executive, the clarity and robustness of electoral endorsement are paramount.
- Third-Place Winner Phenomenon: The system's design, which can catapult a third-place candidate to victory, might be seen as a democratic innovation or a flaw. This reflects the broader debate on whether elections should prioritize majority rule or aim for a consensus candidate.
- Legitimacy and Representation: The potential for a candidate with limited initial support to win post-preference redistribution touches on critical debates about democratic legitimacy. It challenges the electorate and lawmakers to consider what constitutes a 'fair' or 'desirable' outcome in democratic elections.
Legal and Political Implications
This voting system's adoption for electing a powerful executive, such as a president, carries profound legal and political implications. In contexts where traditional parties are unpopular, or electoral landscapes are fragmented, the system's mechanics could indeed facilitate the emergence of a compromise president. While some might view this as ensuring governability and moderation, others could argue it introduces a loophole that undermines the principle of direct majority rule.
The Global Context: A Comparative Perspective
The proposed system resonates with broader trends in electoral reforms worldwide, where nations grapple with enhancing democratic participation, representation, and legitimacy. For instance, variations of ranked-choice and preferential voting have been implemented in different jurisdictions, each with unique outcomes and lessons.
Conclusion: A Reflection on Democratic Values
The exploration of this voting system illuminates the complex interplay between electoral mechanics and democratic values. While it offers a novel approach to ensuring broader representation, it also prompts reflection on what constitutes a legitimate mandate in a democracy. As societies evolve and political landscapes shift, the continuous reassessment of electoral systems becomes crucial. Ultimately, the quest for a perfect electoral system may be unending, but it is a testament to the dynamic nature of democracy itself and the universal desire for governance that truly reflects the will of the people.
Comments
Post a Comment